Skip to content

JoIE Blog

The official blog of the Journal of Institutional Economics

Menu
  • Home
  • Latest Posts
  • Editor-in-chief page
  • About this journal
    • Aims
    • Achievements
    • Citation Impact
    • Subscribe
    • Notes for Contributors
    • Editors
    • International Advisory Board
    • Journal Issues
    • Elinor Ostrom Prize
    • Conflict of Interest Policy
  • Contact
Menu

Beyond Private Property Versus Public Property:

Posted on September 19, 2022September 19, 2022 by Nikhilesh Sinha

The Solution to Douglass. C. North’s Puzzle Concerning China’s Household Responsibility System

Summary of JOIE article (15 October 2021) by Simon Deakin and Gaofeng Meng, Centre for Business Research, University of Cambridge, Cambridge, UK. The full article is available on the JOIE website.

The dominant theory of property in economics views property rights as individualised and private in nature. Private property in conjunction with the free market is then equated with capitalism, and public property and central planning with socialism. This disjunction owes much to the influential work of Harold Demsetz (2002: S658), which posited the ‘alternatives of private and collective ownership’ as ‘simply, capitalism and socialism’. Demsetz (1967) argued that communal ownership, in which the bundle of property rights is divided among the members of a group, can be expected to develop into private ownership over time because of the latter’s implications for efficient cost internalization and the alignment of investments and returns (Demsetz, 1967). Demsetz was echoing here the juridical description of property contained in Blackstone’s Commentaries of 1766 (Blackstone, (2016) [1766]), according to which ownership is ‘that sole and despotic dominion which one man claims and exercises over the external things of the world, in total exclusion of the right of any other individual in the universe’.

Douglass C. North also foregrounded the role of property rights in promoting economic growth. He cited Demsetz’s theory as ‘the intellectual origins’ of his own approach (North and Thomas, 1973: 159). Adapting Demsetz, North and Thomas (1973) drew a distinction between developed and underdeveloped property rights. For them, it was the evolution from the ‘underdeveloped’ common property of the Middle Ages to the liberal concept of full ownership that underpinned the rise of the West. The feudal system was based on a form of ‘split ownership’ in which ‘several persons had jurisdiction or held and shared particular rights to the same piece of land’ (North and Thomas, 1973: 63). With the rise of the enclosure movement from the late Middle Ages onwards, the dominant conception of property rights became one which allowed the individual proprietor to exclude the wider community from access to land (North and Thomas, 1973: 151–153).

Underpinning this development was the emergence of a state capable of defining ‘the formal economic rules of the game’ (North, 2005a: 57). In his work with Barry Weingast (North and Weingast, 1989), North identified the legal and political changes following the ‘Glorious Revolution’ of 1688, which he saw as securing private property rights against state expropriation, as the foundation for the British Industrial Revolution and, more generally, for the rise of capitalism in the West. Developing this theme, North (1990) argued for institutions with the feature of ‘adaptive efficiency’. Whether an economy was moving in an adaptively efficient direction depended on how far its institutions provided ‘incentives to encourage the development of decentralized decision-making processes’ (North, 1990: 81). Although North believed that England’s historical trajectory was distinct, he also thought that it reflected a tendency of economies across the West which was mirrored in the experience of other countries including the USA and France (North et al., 2009). The implication of this approach is that the legal-institutional model of Western economies represents the ‘end-point’ of economic development (Faundez, 2016: 373).

North applied his theory to other cases, including China.  North understood that China’s system of rural land ownership, the Household Responsibility System (HRS), did not observe the model of individualised and private property rights that he saw as responsible for the rise of the West, and was ready to recognize the challenge to his own theories that it posed. He was aware that ‘China had succeeded where other countries had failed’ by avoiding ‘slavishly imitating Western institutions’ (North, 2005b: 159). China, he thought, ‘has no clearly specified property rights and it has a judicial system that is essentially arbitrary’ (North, 2004: 5), a feature of its development which he described as ‘puzzling’. At the same time, North thought that Chinese institutions could be expected to converge with those of the West over the course of time (North, 2005a).

The way to resolve North’s ‘puzzle’ lies, we suggest, in considering other theories of ownership, which may better explain the evolution of the HRS.  The HRS has many of the features of what the jurist A.M. Honoré (1961) called ‘split ownership’ and, relatedly, of the concept of the common pool resource (CPR), which was developed by the political scientist Elinor Ostrom.  

Contrary to North’s suggestion that there are no clearly specified property rights in China, the HRS does set out the respective rights of households and communities.  Individual households have the right to manage their land and to benefit from its use, but they do not have rights of alienation; the land reverts to the collective after a certain period of time has elapsed. The individual right of alienation was regarded by Demsetz (1967) as a core property right, and arguably the most important of all; Ostrom, by contrast, noted that many CPRs operated without there being a right of individual alienation, and that, moreover, its absence was often key to maintaining collective resources over time (Ostrom and Hess, 2017: 17).

A further feature of CPRs is the emergent and communal nature of the rules underpinning them.  The HRS emerged out of community-level initiatives in the late 1970s before being taken up by county and provincial-level governments and eventually embedded in national legislation. The  local roots of the HRS recall the observation of Ostrom and Basurto (2011, 322) that ‘we must understand the process of rule change at a community level’, alongside more formal legal institutions. The HRS is characteristic of the polycentric processes of rule formation which Ostrom characterized as ‘rich mixtures of “private-like” and “public-like” institutions, defying classification into a sterile dichotomy’ of public versus private (1990: 14). 

Is China on a path to transforming itself from a planned economy to a market economy, with private property rights, in the long term?  If so, would this amount to ‘success’?  Ronald Coase (2010) was of the view that ‘economies have different systems of property rights’ and that the ‘common classification of private versus public property rights, the former associated with capitalism and the latter with socialism, is too simplified a view.  He also thought that ‘China will develop its own system of property rights’. Perhaps Coase, rather than North, will prove to be correct on this point.  


References

Blackstone, W. (2016) [1766], Commentaries on the Laws of England (Vol. 2), Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Coase R. and Wang N (2010). Coase Interview (clemson.edu), https://www.clemson.edu/centers-institutes/iep/documents/coase-interview.pdf

Demsetz, H. (1967), ‘Toward a Theory of Property Rights’, American Economic Review, 57(2): 347–359.

Demsetz, H. (2002), ‘Toward a Theory of Property Rights II: The Competition Between Private and Collective Ownership’, Journal of Legal Studies, 31(S2): S653–S672.

Faundez, J. (2016), ‘Douglass North’s Theory of Institutions: Lessons for Law and Development’, Hague Journal on the Rule of Law, 8(2): 373–419.

Honoré, A. M. (1961), ‘Ownership’, in A. G. Guest (ed.), Oxford Essays in Jurisprudence, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 107–147.

North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 

North, D. C. (2004), ‘Institutions and the Performance of Economies over Time’, in A. Liebenthal, O. Feinstein, and G. Ingram (eds), Evaluation and Development: The Partnership Dimension, New Brunswick and New Jersey: Transactions Publishers, pp. 1–7. 

North, D.C. (2005a), ‘The Chinese Menu (for Development)’, The Wall Street Journal, 7 April 2005, https://www.wsj.com/ articles/SB111283514152300351. 

North, D. C. (2005b), Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton: Princeton University Press. 

North, D. C. and R. P. Thomas (1973), The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 

North, D. C. and B. R. Weingast (1989), ‘Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England’, Journal of Economic History, 49(4): 803–832. 

North, D. C., J. J. Wallis and B. R. Weingast (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 

Ostrom, E. and X. Basurto (2011), ‘Crafting Analytical Tools to Study Institutional Change’, Journal of Institutional Economics(2011), 7: 3, 317–343.

Ostrom, E. and C. Hess (2007), ‘Private and Common Property Rights’, workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University. Indiana University, Bloomington: School of Public & Environmental Affairs Research Paper No. 2008-11-01, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1936062 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1936062.


Share on facebook
Facebook
Share on google
Google
Share on twitter
Twitter
Share on linkedin
Linkedin

Leave a Reply Cancel reply

You must be logged in to post a comment.

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

Related Links

Cambridge University Press

Journal of Institutional Economics homepage

Millennium Economics Ltd

WINIR

Search the site

Find posts by keywords

Africa Anti-corruption Article summary Central Bank Independence Competition convention COVID-19 Cultural dimensions Culture Custom Democracy developing economies dynamical systems Economic freedom enmbeddedness Entreprensurship FDI Financial Institutions formal institutions game theory historical GIS Hofstede informal institutions infrastructure institutional economics institutional effectiveness Institutional trust institutions Knight Mortgage norms paradigm Political institutions polycentric governance property rights Property rights to land public goods restrictions rule of law state capacity Symposium on Corporations trust Uganda Uncategorized United States

Categories

  • Article Summary (45)
  • Blog Editor Post (2)
  • Uncategorized (1)

Archives

  • September 2022
  • June 2022
  • March 2022
  • November 2021
  • September 2021
  • June 2021
  • May 2021
  • April 2021
  • January 2021
  • November 2020
  • September 2020
  • July 2020
  • June 2020
  • April 2020
  • March 2020
  • October 2019
  • May 2019
  • April 2019
  • March 2019
  • February 2019
  • October 2017
  • September 2017
  • August 2017
  • July 2017
  • June 2017
©2023 JoIE Blog | Built using WordPress and Responsive Blogily theme by Superb